The Macroeconomics Effects of Government Spending Under Fiscal Foresight

AuthorRuthira Naraidoo,Charl Jooste
Published date01 March 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/saje.12151
Date01 March 2017
THE MACROECONOMICS EFFECTS OF GOVERNMENT
SPENDING UNDER FISCAL FORESIGHT
CHARL JOOSTE
AND RUTHIRA NARAIDOO*
Abstract
Consumption and output responses to fiscal shocks are studied in a model with fiscal foresight.
Fiscal foresight reduces both output multipliers and consumption. However, key features such as
sticky wages, credit constrained households and elastic labour supply, are able to generate both
sizeable output multipliers and positive consumption, in effect preserving key Keynesian effects.
This model fits a developing economy like South Africa well since it is able to capture transpar-
ent communication of government as well as control for credit constrained consumption and
sticky wages.
JEL Classification: E12, E32, E62, H30, H31
Keywords: General equilibrium, fiscal spending, foresight
1. INTRODUCTION
This paper disentangles the effects of fiscal shocks when agents have foresight. As high-
lighted by Ramey (2011) and Leeper et al. (2012) models that do not explicitly account
for foresight is misspecified and may produce faulty output and consumption responses
to fiscal shocks. To address the issue of foresight we build on the familiar models of Gali
et al. (2007) and Furlanetto (2011). We investigate whether certain conditions (sticky
wages, share of rule-of-thumb consumption and elastic labour supply) are able to pre-
serve the results of Gali et al. (2007) and Furlanetto (2011) under foresight, or whether
they will inevitably complement the results obtained by Ramey (2011). The Gali et al.
(2007) model requires an exogenous wage mark-up shock along with a large share of
rule-of-thumb consumers to generate positive aggregate household consumption
responses given a fiscal shock. Furlanetto’s (2011) sticky wage model still generate posi-
tive consumption responses despite a fall in household wages due to the beneficial effect
of lower interest rate response. The two models are closely related and are appropriate
for our study in trying to analyse whether foresight eliminates positive consumption.
These models are also well-suited to developing economies like South Africa and capture
essential features such as union bargaining on wages, credit constrained households,
sticky prices reflecting the monopolistic competition in the market (Fedderke and Schal-
ing, 2005), investment adjustment costs and transparent communication by government
on future spending and taxes.
The paper has two contributions. The first shows that fiscal foresight eliminates the
results obtained in Gali et al. (2007), i.e. consumption does not increase with respect to
* Corresponding author: Faculty of Economics and Management Sciences, Department of
Economics, University of Pretoria, Pretoria 0002, South Africa.
E-mail: ruthira.naraidoo@up.ac.za
University of Pretoria
V
C2017 Economic Society of South Africa. doi: 10.1111/saje.12151
68
South African Journal of Economics Vol. 85:1 March 2017
South African Journal
of Economics
an increase in fiscal spending and consequently that a large share of rule-of-thumb con-
sumption is not enough to preserve their original results. The second contribution shows
that sticky wages, as in the model of Furlanetto (2011), minimises the negative impact of
fiscal foresight. Under certain calibrations we show that with sticky wages one can still
generate positive consumption responses and produce sizeable output multipliers.
It is important from the outset to highlight why sticky wages produce such different
results. The main difference follows from labour supply and in particular how wages
react. Since the model contains lump sum taxes, any increase in fiscal spending today
will have to be financed through higher taxes in the future. The lump sum tax, although
not distortionary, shifts the consumers’ budget constraint to the left. Consequently, opti-
mising consumers reduce their consumption immediately. This negative wealth effect
induces consumers to supply more labour, which results in a decrease in the real wage
(see Ramey 2011). Here sticky wages ensure that the fall in real wages is muted. A sec-
ond channel is also at play – an increase in fiscal spending increases prices through an
increase in aggregate demand, which increases the monetary policy rate. Higher interest
rates reduce investment and decreases consumption even more. Under sticky prices and
wages, prices and wages are less prone to a government shock and hence interest rates are
muted and have less of an effect on consumption. This result also holds for news shocks.
We add two types of foresight, viz., medium and high to fiscal shocks, which comple-
ments the works by both Gali et al. (2007) and Leeper et al. (2012) in investigating fiscal
expansions. Finally, we provide sensitivity analysis as to how the model behaves under
different labour supply elasticities and different shares of rule-of-thumb consumption.
Given that the response of labour is crucial within the context of consumption
response to government spending, we argue that elastic labour supply along with sticky
wages counters the negative effects of foresight on consumption even more. With a large
share of rule-of-thumb consumption and elastic labour typical of most developing coun-
tries, some of the Gali et al. (2007) results, sign not size, are preserved.
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
The effects of foresight have become increasingly important in trying to explain differen-
ces in empirical and theoretical work on the macroeconomic consequences of fiscal
shocks. Blanchard and Perotti’s (2002) paper serves as reference point for the majority of
empirical work and has been highly contested by Ramey (2011). While there seems to
be some agreement on the effects of government spending on output, there exists a major
disagreement regarding the effects of spending shocks on consumption and wages. Some
authors find strong evidence of Keynesian effects – both consumption and wages increase
in response to spending (Rotemberg and Woodford, 1992; Blanchard and Perotti, 2002;
Gali et al., 2007), while others show that household consumption decreases when gov-
ernment spending increases (Baxter and King, 1983; Ramey and Shapiro, 1998; Hall,
2009; Cogan et al., 2009, Farmer and Plotnikov, 2012).
Ramey and Shapiro (1998), Ramey (2011) and Leeper et al. (2012) argue that many
shocks identified from the standard VAR are anticipated changes in government spend-
ing and are not pure government spending shocks. Some agents have information about
future spending and tax policy changes before they are implemented, especially when
governments communicate transparently. This is called fiscal foresight. This often arises
due to pre-announced policy changes, legislative lags or simple policy implementation
69South African Journal of Economics Vol. 85:1 March 2017
V
C2017 Economic Society of South Africa.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT