The Elasticity of Taxable Income: The Case of South Africa

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/saje.12232
AuthorJohannes Hermanus Kemp
Date01 December 2019
Published date01 December 2019
© 2019 Economic Society of Sout h Africa
South African Journal of Economics Vol. 87:4 December 2019
doi : 10.1111/ saje .122 32
417
THE ELASTICITY OF TAXABLE INCOME: THE CASE OF
SOUTH AFRICA
JOHANN ES HERMA NUS KEMP*
Abstract
A key tax policy parameter that has received much attention in the international literature, but
about which there is substantial uncertainty, is the overall elasticity of taxable income. The size of
this parameter is central to the formulation of tax and transfer policy, as well as for the study of
the welfare implications of tax decisions. This paper uses a panel of individual tax returns for the
period 2009–2013 and the phenomenon of “bracket creep” to construct instrumental variable
estimates of the sensitivity of income to changes in tax rates. Estimates suggest that the overall
elasticity of taxable income is approximately 0.3, while that of broad income is significantly lower.
The overall response is primarily driven by the elastic response of taxable income for high-income
earners, who have an elasticity of closer to 0.4. Using the elasticity estimates within an optimal tax
framework, it is determined that the optimal marginal tax rate for the top 10% of income earners
is broadly in line with the current income tax schedule. However, results also suggest that there is
little scope for raising marginal rates on high-income earners further without inducing a negative
revenue response.
JEL Classification: H21, H31, J22
Keywords: Fiscal polic y, elasticity, taxable income, optimal tax pol icy
1. INTRODUCTION
The behavioural response of ta xpayers to changes in (marginal) tax rates ha s long been of
interest to economists. The size of this para meter is central to the formulation of tax and
transfer policy, as well as for the study of the welfa re implications of tax decisions. Public
finance practitioners are often asked to predict responses to alternative policy changes
and to provide empirical estimates of the effec ts to decision-makers (Thoresen a nd Vattø,
2013). To this end, it is important to quantify the behavioural response of taxpayers to
changing policy parameters.
In this regard, the ela sticity of taxable income, or ETI, is a key concept. The ETI aims
to capture all possible behavioural responses to changes in income taxation, including
tax evasion and/or avoidance, in a single measu re, without the need to specify the natu re
of the specific adjustment processes involved (Creedy, 2009; Thoresen and Vattø, 2013).1
This allows policymakers to evaluate the likely impact of policy proposals on both
1 These adjustments could include la bour supply changes (at both the extensive and/or intensive
margins), income shifting between sources which are taxed at different rates and ta x evasion
through non-declar ation of income.
* Corresponding author: Bureau f or Economic Resea rch, Stellenbosch University, Stellenbosch,
South Africa. E-ma il: jhkemp@sun.ac.za
South African Journal
of Economics
418 South African Journal of Economics Vol. 87:4 December 2019
© 2019 Economic Society of Sout h Africa
taxpayer behaviour and policy outcomes (such as the impact on tax revenue of a change
in marginal tax rates).
Modelling the response to tax rates in this reduced form way, as opposed to formu-
lating a structura l model of the behaviour involved, has proven to be very attractive. As
mentioned in Saez et al. (2012), a large body of literature has sought to estimate the ETI
and elasticities for related income measures. Most of this literature has focused on indi-
vidual taxable income in the United States, Ca nada and Western Europe, while a limited
number of studies have focused on countries outside these regions.
Very little work has been done in the South African context. Given the lack of access
to micro-level panel data on personal income taxes (PIT ), studies that have attempted to
estimate the ETI for South Africa focus primarily on publicly available aggregated tax
data. Using a new dataset comprising conf idential tax return data made available for
research purposes by the South A frican Revenue Service (SARS) and the National
Treasury, this paper attempts to estimate the ETI for South Africa. Given the impor-
tance of PIT in overall tax collection in South Africa (personal income tax is the single
largest contributor to tax revenue, accounting for 35% of total gross tax collected be-
tween 2000 and 2018), the study is restricted to estimating the ETI as it applies to per-
sonal income taxes and individual marginal tax rates.2
Much of the recent literature uses tax reforms to identify t he parameters of interest when
studying the sensitivity of income with respect to marginal tax rates. Notwithstanding
the fact that the ETI va ries between countries depending on the nature of the tax s ystem,
the empirical literature has failed to generate a consensus of the size of the elasticity –
even within specific countries.
According to Saez (2003), two reasons might explain this lack of consensus. First,
most tax reforms introduce numerous changes to the definition of taxable income be-
sides tax rate changes. This makes it difficult to compare reported income before and
after a tax reform. Second, most studies rely on a comparison between high- and low- or
middle-income taxpayers. The former often experience large tax rate changes after any
given tax reform, while the latter experience little or no change in marginal tax rates.
This suggests t hat the research design for estimating behavioura l responses to changes
in marginal tax rates should meet two conditions. First, the tax change should affect
only marginal ta x rates without introducing changes in tax rules. Sec ond, the tax cha nge
should affect dif ferently groups of taxpayers that a re comparable in terms of incomes and
other economic characteristics (Saez, 2003).
Taking these factors into account and considering the fact that there was no large
legislated tax reforms in South Africa over our sample period, we follow Saez (2003) in
utilising the phenomenon of “bracket creep” to estimate the behavioural response of ta x-
payers with respect to changing marginal tax rates. Because of inf lation, a taxpayer near
the top end of an income tax bracket might ’creep’ to the next bracket even if their real
income does not change. This is especially true if nominal income tax brackets are not
2 While the la rger share of the international literature ha s also focused on personal income ta xes
(PIT) and the response of individuals to changes in marginal tax rates, most of the conceptual
and empirical issue s discussed remain releva nt for other tax bases, such as corporate i ncome taxes
(CIT ).
419South African Journal of Economics Vol. 87:4 December 2019
© 2019 Economic Society of Sout h Africa
fully adjusted for inflation (so-called fiscal drag). In contrast, taxpayers at the bottom
end of the relevant tax bracket are unlikely to experience an increase in marginal rates.
In practice, the method compares changes in the incomes of taxpayers near the top
end of a bracket to those taxpayers at the bottom end of the bracket using tax return
data. Importantly, “bracket creep” does not affect the definition of reported income.
Therefore, incomes can be easily compared across years. Additionally, this strategy com-
pares groups of taxpayers that are closely related in terms of income levels and economic
characteristics.
Using this approach, the elasticity for ta xable income is estimated at around 0.3, while
that for broad income is estimated at closer to 0.2. Additionally, it was found that be-
havioural responses are concentrated in higher income groups as suggested by the higher
elasticity estimate (0.37 for taxable income) for the top 10% of income earners.
Two limitations of the approach should be mentioned. First, changes in tax rates due
to “bracket creep” are relatively small compared to other ta x reforms across the decades.
Second, because “bracket creep” is not a legislated tax change, it might be harder for
taxpayers to understand the ef fect of this change on their after-tax income, and therefore
the behavioural response to “bracket cre ep” might be muted. This sugges ts that ETI esti-
mates obtained using “bracket creep” ref lect a lower bound for the behavioural response
to changing tax rates.
An important application of ETI estimates is in the determination of optimal mar-
ginal tax rates. Most studies on optimal tax ation focus on the top 1% of income earners.
However, due to data limitations, this paper focuses on the top 10% of income earners.
Embedding the elasticity estimate of 0.37 for the top 10% of income earners in an opti-
mal tax fra mework, it is determined that the optimal marginal tax rate for this group is
around 48% (consistent with a legislated marginal PIT rate of around 40%).
The rest of the paper proceeds as follow. Section 2 discusses the basic conceptual
framework and unpacks the various identification issues that arise when attempting to
estimate the ETI in practice. Section 2 also provides a short review of the international
empirical literature. Section 3 estimates the ETI for South Africa using micro-level tax
return data and Section 4 discusses optimal ta xation results. Section 5 presents some
caveats a nd concludes.
2. CONCEPTUAL FR AMEWORK AND LI TERATURE R EVIEW
In the basic ETI model3, individuals maximise a utility function u(c, l), where c is the
consumption (equal to disposable income in a one-period model) and l is the labour sup-
ply (measured by hours worked). Earnings are given by w·l, where w is the exogenous
wage rate. The (linearised) budget constraint is c = w·l·(1−τ) + R, where τ is the marginal
tax rate and R is the virtual income (i.e. non-wage income equal to the intercept of the
linear section of the budget constraint extended to the c axis, where l = 0).
The ETI literature generalises this model by noting that hours worked is just one of
the possible behavioural responses to income taxation. As shown in Feldstein (1999), a
simple way to jointly model these responses is to assume that utility depends positively
on disposable income (equal to consumption) c and negatively on reported or taxable
3 Following Saez (2001), Gruber and Saez (2002) and Saez et al. (2012)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT