International Institutional Attitude towards Holding Company Regimes: Curbing International Tax Avoidance

JurisdictionSouth Africa
AuthorThabo Legwaila
Published date20 August 2019
Date20 August 2019
Pages159-200
Articles
INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTIONAL
ATTITUDE TOWARDS HOLDING COMPANY
REGIMES: CURBING INTERNATIONAL TAX
AVOIDANCE
THABO LEGWAILA*
Professor, Department of Mercantile Law, University of Johannesburg
I INTRODUCTION
Depending on their stages in economic development, different countries
view holding companies and jurisdictions that are conducive to holding
companies operations differently. During the developmental stages,
most countries go to great lengths to attract foreign direct investment to
their shores. Countries with adequate infrastructure have the benef‌it of
attracting foreign direct investment through the availability of such
infrastructure.
Fundamental determinants such as market size, access to raw materi-
als and the availability of skilled labour are primary factors in attracting
foreign direct investment. A suitable tax regime plays a secondary role in
attracting foreign direct investment. The absence of fundamental deter-
minants, and therefore adequate infrastructure, often results in coun-
tries relying on the tax system to attract investment.
Countries engaging in activities that are intended to attract develop-
ment are constantly at the risk of crossing the Rubicon from what is seen
to be fair competition to what is internationally deemed to be crude and
unacceptable tax competition. Certain developed countries, in an
attempt to broaden their tax bases, also engage in this unacceptable
competition. Such unacceptable and unfair competition is referred to as
harmful tax competition. This is practised broadly by tax havens and
those countries whose tax regimes are harmfully preferential.
*B Iuris (Venda), LLB, LLM (Wits), PG Dip Tax Law, LLM (UCT), LLD (UP). This article
is an adapted version of part of my doctoral thesis at the University of Pretoria entitled The
Suitability of the South African Corporate Tax Regime for the Use of South African Resident
Intermediary Holding Companies (2010).
159
(2016) 28 SA Merc LJ 159
© Juta and Company (Pty) Ltd
This article discusses the measures that are used to curb international
tax avoidance. The purpose of the article is to highlight three levels of
curbing international tax avoidance as a general matter which are (i)
unilateral measures by individual countries, (ii) multilateral methods
that are used by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD) as best practice to curb international tax avoid-
ance and (iii) bilateral measures that can be incorporated into bilateral
treaties by treaty partner countries. These measures inevitably, and often
inadvertently, affect holding companies adversely. This analysis is
necessitated by the vast interest in various countries to introduce tax
regimes that are suitable for holding companies (in various forms,
including headquarter companies and intermediary holding compa-
nies), which has the potential of making such countries tax havens,
preferential tax regimes or offshore f‌inancial centres.
1
II HARMFUL TAX COMPETITION
According to Rohatgi, ‘[h]armful competition arises due to mismatches
in the existing tax systems of countries that can be exploited by
taxpayers. Such economic behaviour may be considered as unacceptable
tax avoidance by certain countries since they believe that it undermines
the integrity and fairness of their tax systems’.
2
The term ‘harmful tax
competition’ broadly refers to the tax practices that are adopted by
1
On South Africa, see National Treasury Budget Review (2011) 73. See also Lermer, ‘2010
Budget attracts SA based headquarter companies — PwC’ Moneyweb 18 February 2010,
available at http://www.moneyweb.co.za/mw/view/mw/en/page302588?oid=347864&sn=
2009%20Detail, accessed on 1 June 2015; the most prominent of the other countries are
Mauritius (See Lowtax: Global Tax & Business Portal, ‘Mauritius: Domestic Corporate
Taxation’, available at http://www.lowtax.net/lowtax/html/jmudctx.html, accessed on 12
June 2015; Oleynic Mauritius Tax Guide (2006) (unpublished); Legwaila, ‘The tax treatment
of holding companies in Mauritius: Lessons for South Africa’ (2011) 23(1) SAMLJ 1. On the
Netherlands, see also Lambooij & Portengen, ‘Netherlands — Holding Companies’ (2008),
available at http://online2.ibfd.org/collections/hold/html/hold_nl.html, accessed on 1 June
2015, Lambooij & Peelen, ‘The Netherlands Holding Company — Past and Present’ (2006)
Bulletin for International Taxation 4.1; ‘Netherland Holding Company Overview’,available at
http://www.ocra.com/solutions/eu_holding/Netherlands.asp, accessed on 1 June 2015. On
the United Kingdom, see also Collinson et al, Tiley and Collinson: UK Tax Guide 2006–2007
(LexisNexis UK 2006); Watterson, Corporation Tax 2008/2009 (IBFD 2008) 49; Deloitte
‘Comparison of European holding company regimes’, available at https://www.deloitte.com/
assets/Dcom-Global/Local%20Assets/Documents/Tax/dtt_tax_holdcomatrix_europe_
072309.pdf,accessed on 19 March 2015; Kavanagh, ‘New U.K. participation exemption for
capital gains on substantial shareholdings’(2002) 13(8) Journal of International Taxation 24.
On Belgium, see also Vanhaute, Belgium in International Tax Planning (IBFD 2008) 94. See
also Ernst & Young, Worldwide Corporate Tax Guide (2006) 130; Deloitte, ‘Holding
companies in Belgium’, available at http://www.deloitte.com/dtt/cda/doc/content/
Holding%20Companies%20in%20Belgium.pdf, accessed on 1 June 2015.
2
Rohatgi, Basic International Taxation (Kluwer Law International 2005) 85.
(2016) 28 SA MERC LJ160
© Juta and Company (Pty) Ltd
countries to exploit the weaknesses in the international tax rules in other
countries.
3
It needs to be noted that by using the tax system to attract foreign
investors, countries are exercising their right to f‌iscal sovereignty.
4
In
this regard, it is acknowledged that tax competition cannot always be
bad. It does have positive attributes. At the Commonwealth Finance
Ministers’ Meeting held in Malta in September 2000 ‘[m]inisters
recognised that tax competition could in fact be helpful, and not
harmful, because it can further spur governments to create f‌iscal
environments conducive to generating growth and employment’.
5
In the same positive approach to tax competition, Friedman stated the
following:
6
‘Competition among national governments in the public services they
provide and in the taxes they impose is every bit as productive as
competition among individuals or enterprises in the goods and services
they offer for sale and the prices at which they offer them. Both lead to
variety and innovation; to improvement in the quality of the goods and
services and a reduction in their cost. A governmental cartel is no less
damaging than a private cartel.’
A contrary and more popular viewpoint is that tax competition is
dreadful and appalling. The proponents of this view see tax competition
as resulting in a destructive ‘race to the bottom’. This negative view is
ref‌lected by Ault as follows:
7
‘Tax competition causes ‘‘bidding wars’’ in competing for mobile activi-
ties, ultimately resulting in no tax at all on mobile capital; it makes
redistributive non-benef‌its-based income taxation impossible; it may
require states to shift to other revenue sources, taxing less mobile activities
3
See Olivier & Honiball, International Tax — A South African Perspective 5 ed (Siber Ink
2008) 575; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) report,
‘Harmful Tax Competition: An Emerging Global Issue’ (1998) 1–19. See also Oguttu, Curbing
Offshore Tax Avoidance: The Case of South African Companies and Trusts (LLD dissertation,
University of South Africa, 2007) 10–14.
4
Biswas, International Tax Competition: Globalisation and Fiscal Sovereignty (Common-
wealth Secretariat 2002) 1: ‘Fiscal sovereignty is a right which has been carefully guarded by
sovereign states and protected in international law over hundreds of years; international f‌iscal
disputes have provoked major international political upheavals... .’
5
Commonwealth Finance Ministers’ Meeting, September 2000, available at http://
www.thecommonwealth.org/document/181889/34293/35232/152088/153876/
commonwealth_f‌inance_ministers_meeting_st_julians.htm, accessed on 6 August 2015.
6
In a speech delivered by Emeritus Professor Milton Friedman from the University of
Chicago at the Hoover Institution, Stanford University in May 2001.
7
Ault, ‘Tax Competition: What (if anything) to do about it?’ in Van Raad (ed),
International and Comparative Taxation: Essays in Honour of Klaus Vogel (Kluwer Law
International 2002) 2.
INTERNATIONAL HOLDING COMPANY REGIMES: CURBING TAX 161
© Juta and Company (Pty) Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT