Inflation in South Africa: An Assessment of Alternative Inflation Models

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/saje.12192
AuthorYang Liu,Johannes Fedderke
Date01 June 2018
Published date01 June 2018
INFLATION IN SOUTH AFRICA: AN ASSESSMENT OF
ALTERNATIVE INFLATION MODELS
JOHANNES FEDDERKE*AND YANG LIU
Abstract
We consider the relative empirical performance of a range of inflation models for South Africa.
Model coverage is of Phillips curve, New Keynesian Phillips curve, monetarist and structural
models of inflation. Our core findings are that the single most robust covariate of inflation is
unit labour cost. We further decompose unit labour cost into changes in the nominal wage and
real labour productivity. The principal association is a strong positive relationship between infla-
tion and nominal wages, while improvements in real labour productivity report only a relatively
weak negative association with inflation. Supply-side shocks also consistently report an association
with inflation. As to demand-side shocks, the output gap does not return a robust statistical asso-
ciation with inflation. Instead, it is growth in the money supply and government expenditure
which return robust and theoretically consistent associations with inflationary pressure.
JEL Classification: E31
Keywords: Inflation, South Africa
1 INTRODUCTION
What accounts for inflationary pressures in the South African economy?
Inflation has received a disproportionate amount of attention in the South African macro-
economic literature. Unusually for South African debates, empirically motivated papers on
inflation have shown a close adherence to theoretical priors. A core feature of the South Afri-
can empirical studies has been a resolute search for a Phillips curve type of trade-off between
prices and demand-side inflationary pressure and real economic activity. A second constant
that emerges from the empirical literature is the consistent failure to successfully support the
Phillips curve trade-off.
1
Instead, a far more pervasive finding in the South African empirical
literature has been a strong association between inflation and wage costs.
Given the extensive struggle surrounding confirmatory evidence in support of the
Phillips curve, a further surprise in the South African empirical inflation literature is the
very limited search over alternative theoretical accounts of inflation. Thus very few stud-
ies even consider monetary accounts of inflation. Nor is there much evidence of an
exploitation of the well-established link between the first and second moments of the
* Corresponding author: Professor, Pennsylvania State University, 237 Katz, State College, PA
16802, USA. E-mail: jwf15@psu.edu
Center of New Structural Economics, Peking University
1
The principal exception we have found in the South African literature is associated with a New
Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) estimation, but which has to abandon adherence to the rational
expectations foundations of the NKPC by allowing for habit persistence, and which has to esti-
mate under the assumption of perfectly clearing and flexible markets – something of a reach in the
South African context (see Burger and Du Plessis, 2013).
V
C2018 Economic Society of South Africa. doi: 10.1111/saje.12192
197
South African Journal of Economics Vol. 86:2 June 2018
South African Journal
of Economics
inflation time series.
2
This is all the more surprising since a cursory consideration of
South African inflation suggests that Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity
(ARCH) structure is plausible both for the Consumer Price Index (CPI) and Gross
Domestic Product (GDP) deflator time series (see Fig. 1).
The current paper innovates in three distinct senses in relation to the South African
debate.
First, we consider the relative performance of a range of alternative inflation models.
This includes, but is not restricted to Phillips curve type models of inflation. We extend
consideration to long-run structural models of price determination, a New Keynesian
Phillips curve (NKPC) model and monetary models of inflation.
Second, we consider the utility of incorporating ARCH structure into the modelling
in improving the performance of inflation models. We do so across the full range of the-
oretical alternatives, with the exception of the structural model where econometric con-
siderations preclude this possibility. A crucial means of considering the relative
performance of the inflation models is not only goodness of fit of the models, but also
their forecast performance over a 12-quarter window at the end of the sample period
under consideration in this study.
Third, unlike previous studies we abandon theoretical purity. Instead, we allow for all
the potential covariates of inflation identified under the alternative theoretical models to
compete empirically, in order to establish their relative robustness in modelling inflation.
In summary, our core findings are that the single most robust covariate of inflation is
unit labour cost. We further decompose unit labour cost into changes in the nominal
wage and real labour productivity. The principal association is a strong positive relation-
ship between inflation and nominal wages, while improvements in real labour productiv-
ity report only a relatively weak negative association with inflation. Supply-side shocks
also consistently report an association with inflation. As to demand-side shocks, the out-
put gap does not return a robust statistical association with inflation. Instead, growth in
Figure 1. Inflation under CPI and GDP deflator [Colour figure can be viewed at
wileyonlinelibrary.com]
2
After all, the seminal Engle (1982) introduction of ARCH estimation focussed precisely on
inflation.
198 South African Journal of Economics Vol. 86:2 June 2018
V
C2018 Economic Society of South Africa.
the money supply and government expenditure return more persistent and theoretically
consistent associations with inflationary pressure.
The difficulty in finding a reliable impact of the output gap on inflation may well be
due to the difficulties in developing reliable output gap measures (see Fedderke and Men-
gisteab, 2017). But precisely given this limitation, it may be desirable to use alternative
measures of demand-side pressure instead, such as money supply growth and government
expenditure stances.
The paper is structured as follows. In Section 2 we describe the alternative approaches
to modelling inflation that have been used in South Africa. Section 3 adds important
observations on the modelling of costs of production for inflation models in South
Africa. Section 4 outlines the modelling approach of the current paper and Section 5 the
data we employ. Section 6 presents our results, while Section 7 concludes and evaluates.
2 APPROACHES TO MODELLING SOUTH AFRICAN INFLATION
The simplest possible model of inflation is that agents formulate expectations adaptively.
This approach is devoid of theoretical justification, and issues in the time series model
given by:
Ept
ðÞ5b01X
k
i51
bipt2i1et(1)
where Edenotes the mathematical expectations operator, p
t
is the inflation rate in period
t,andetdenotes the error term. Despite the lack of theoretical foundations of this
model, in this study we employ it as a benchmark against which alternatives are judged,
given the surprising empirical resilience of the approach noted by many studies.
A second class of models is based on a structural theoretical framework given by a version
of the Phillips curve. Thus for instance Gordon (1997) (see also Gordon, 1989) proposes:
pt5X
k
i51
aipt2i1X
m
j51
bjDt2j1cct1dzt1et(2)
where D
t
denotes excess demand, c
t
the change in unit labour cost and z
t
supply shocks.
Measures of D
t
are provided by the unemployment gap U2
UðÞwhere Uand
Uare
the actual unemployment rate and the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemploy-
ment (NAIRU), respectively, or the output gap y2yðÞwhere yand yare the log of actual
output and long-run trend or potential output, respectively. Supply shocks are captured
by for instance changes in relative food prices (see Pretorious and Janse van Rensburg,
1996) or real exchange rate shocks. Burger and Marinkov (2006) further extend the Gor-
don model by classifying the excess demand variable D
t
in terms of the extent of infla-
tionary pressure being generated. They do so by including variables for excess demand,
one for excess demand deemed to “overheat” the economy, Doverh
t, another for weak
excess demand Dweak
t.
3
This represents an attempt to capture the possibility of a non-
3
Doverh
tduring the weak-economy years is set to be zero, and symmetrically Dweak
tduring over-
heating periods.
199South African Journal of Economics Vol. 86:2 June 2018
V
C2018 Economic Society of South Africa.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT