HOW EXPOSED IS THE SOUTH AFRICAN ECONOMY TO INTERNATIONAL TRADE?

AuthorL. RANGASAMY,Z. BLIGNAUT
Published date01 September 2005
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1813-6982.2005.00025.x
Date01 September 2005
South African Journal of Economics Vol. 73:3 September 2005©
© 2005 Economic Society of South Africa. Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4
2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA on behalf of ESSA.
366
HOW EXPOSED IS THE SOUTH AFRICAN ECONOMY TO
INTERNATIONAL TRADE?
L. RANGASAMY AND Z. BLIGNAUT1
Abstract
Following the policies implemented during the 1990s, the South African economy has become
more globalised. This is particularly the case as far as international trade is concerned. The
implementation of trade reforms, in some cases faster than WTO commitments, has increased
the exposure of the South African economy to international trade. Trade in intermediate inputs
increases the external orientation of an industry and hence increases the economy’s exposure to
trade. This in effect means that the economy is more open to external trade shocks than is
conveyed by the traditional openness measure which considers only the trade in final products.
This paper uses a measure proposed by Campa and Goldberg (1997) to estimate the exposure to
trade and finds that around 79 per cent of output in 2000 was accounted for by industries that
became more exposed to international trade. Further, domestic production has become more
reliant on imported inputs with around 60 per cent of South Africa’s GDP being accounted for
by industries with a negative external orientation (i.e. industries where imported input costs
exceeded export revenue). In addition, it was also found that those sectors that became more
externally oriented had lower inflation rates and higher growth rates than the other sectors in the
economy for the period under analysis. The extent to which the increased exposure to
international trade facilitated these developments remains topical for further research.
1. INTRODUCTION
This paper analyses South Africa's exposure to international trade, concentrating on the
period after 1990. The economy’s exposure to international trade is measured by
considering its sales (exports) in foreign markets, its competition with foreign products
(imports) in domestic markets and the use of imported inputs in domestic production.
There is little doubt that the South African economy has become more exposed to
international trade during the 1990s.2 However, the analysis to date has generally not
considered the trade in intermediate inputs and as a result the full extent of the
exposure to trade at the sectoral level has not been measured. In this paper trade in
intermediate inputs is also taken into account in order to derive a more comprehensive
measure of the exposure to international trade on a sectoral basis. The paper attempts
to answer the following two questions:
What has been the extent of the exposure to trade of the South African economy
after 1990?
What has been the nature of the trade exposure?
1 Research Department, South African Reserve Bank. We are grateful to an anonymous referee
and Herman Smith of the SARB for useful comments on an earlier draft. Gerhard Bouwer of
Statistics South Africa provided valuable suggestions on the methodological aspects of this
paper. The usual disclaimer applies.
2 For example, Loots (2001) analyses the extent of the globalisation of the South African
economy by considering both investment and trade flows. South Africa is classified as a
moderate globaliser with an economic growth rate of 2,7 per cent - one per cent below the
average for all countries in the same category.
South African Journal of Economics Vol. 73:3 September 2005©
© 2005 Economic Society of South Africa. 367
In the next section the concept of external orientation is highlighted. T he following
two sections then addresses the two questions directly. The penultimate section
appraises the significance of the results. Some concluding remarks are made in the last
section.
2. EXPOSURE TO INTERNATIONAL TRADE: SOME THEORETICAL
CONSIDERATIONS
The empirical literature has traditionally used the "trade openness" measure - calculated
as the sum of final goods imports and exports as a ratio of production - to reflect the
exposure to international trade. This is usually termed the "openness" indicator and is
also often used in empirical analysis to depict the extent of globalisation of an industry.
However, the term globalisation is multi-dimensional and incorporates trans-boundary
flows of goods and services, capital, people, technology, ideas and cultures (Dawson,
2003). The term is thus very broad and any attempt to evaluate whether a country has
become more globalised or not has to consider all these elements. There is however
consensus that the process of economic globalisation incorporates the dismantling and
lowering of tariffs or non tariff barriers, growth in international trade, increased
international financial flows and the exchange of knowledge and technology across
boundaries. For statistical convenience, the economic interpretation of the concept is
usually emphasised in the empirical literature on globalisation. In addition, very often
the problem of data constraints is circumvented by making the assumption that
international trade flows are an appropriate proxy for economic globalisation.3
However, in this paper the emphasis is on the issue of trade openness and not
globalisation per se.
Rodrik (2000) highlights the importance of distinguishing between a "policy
measure" and an "outcome measure" in trade policy analysis. A policy measure refers to
government regulations and policies while an outcome measure, conversely, uses actual
economic outcomes (e.g. international trade flows) to ascertain the degree of economic
openness.4 There is the need to distinguish between policy intentions and actual
outcomes since policy intentions may not match actual outcomes. For example, a policy
of trade liberalisation may have been implemented but prevailing economic conditions
(e.g. imperfect competition) may result in import volumes not increasing to the extent
suggested by the liberalisation measures. On the other hand, there could be an increase
in imports which is not related to the liberalisation programme. The essence of the
argument is that an outcome measure (such as trade flows) may not necessarily reflect
the policy bias of a trade regime (Rodrik, 2000).
In the context of the above argument it is important to highlight the primary
concern of this paper, namely, the economy’s exposure to international trade. The
extent to which the exposure has been shaped by economic policy is not directly
addressed in this paper. The trade openness indicator for the economy can be
expressed as:
3 This is usually the case for research on developing countries where data constraints abound.
4 See for example Sachs, J. and Warner, A. (1995) and Skipton, C. (2002). Bhagwati (1988) argues
that outward orientation is incentive neutral, that is, it does not discriminate against exports.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT