Excessive pricing in South African competition law: Elucidating the nature and implications of the consumer-detriment requirement

JurisdictionSouth Africa
Pages173-218
Citation(2017) 29 SA Merc LJ 173
AuthorRyan David McKerrow
Published date20 August 2019
Date20 August 2019
Articles
EXCESSIVE PRICING IN SOUTH AFRICAN
COMPETITION LAW: ELUCIDATING THE
NATURE AND IMPLICATIONS OF THE
CONSUMER-DETRIMENT REQUIREMENT
RYAN DAVID MCKERROW*
Abstract
Section 8(a) of the Competition Act prohibits dominant f‌irms from
charging excessive prices to the detriment of consumers. In Harmony v
Mittal the Competition Tribunal took the position that the provision’s
reference to consumer detriment was ‘simply a superf‌luous description
of an excessive price rather than a qualif‌ier of its likely effects’. This
article challenges the Tribunal’s relatively static approach to consumer
detriment. It acknowledges that the incorporation of a consumer-
detriment requirement into section 8(a) not only safeguards dominant
f‌irms from prejudice, but also gives rise to a contextually appropriate
consumer-welfare standard. The article argues that consumer detriment
must be evaluated by means of an analysis which adequately accounts
for market dynamics. Following a critical analysis of three pertinent
arguments in favour of non-intervention — the self-correction, innova-
tion, and error-costs arguments — it concludes that the welfare interests
of current and future consumers are not always aligned. As such, net
consumer detriment and an interventionist outcome cannot be the
invariable fate of an excessive price. The appropriate outcome must
therefore be determined on a case-by-case basis.
Keywords: Competition law, anti-trust, abuse of dominance, excessive
pricing, consumer detriment, consumer welfare, market intervention.
*BComm (Hons) LLB (Rhodes) LLM (UCT).
173
(2017) 29 SA Merc LJ 173
© Juta and Company (Pty) Ltd
I INTRODUCTION
Section 8(a) of the Competition Act
1
(‘the Act’) prohibits the charging
of excessive prices by dominant f‌irms where such pricing gives rise to
consumer detriment. This article shows that the consumer-detriment
requirement incorporated into section 8(a) imports into the prohibition
a consumer-welfare standard that is suited to the South African context
— a context shaped by historical imbalance. It is argued that consumer
detriment should be evaluated through a dynamic approach which
accounts for the interests of both current and future consumers. A
critical analysis of three pertinent arguments in favour of non-
intervention in supra-competitive pricing practices — the self-
correction, innovation, and error-costs arguments — demonstrates that
the interests of current and future consumers are not invariably aligned.
On this basis it is contended that, where a price is deemed excessive,
consumer detriment, construed as net detriment to the general con-
sumer body, is not a foregone conclusion. Therefore, a blanket prohibi-
tion cannot be placed on excessive pricing. The proscription of excessive
pricing must be informed by a consumer-detriment enquiry carried out
on a case-by-case basis. This enquiry must necessarily account for the
interplay between legal, market, and social forces. A range of pertinent
considerations are identif‌ied and discussed as a means of edifying and
facilitating the process.
Section II begins with an outline of the legislative framework for the
prohibition of excessive pricing in South Africa. This is followed by an
analysis of its interpretation and application by the competition authori-
ties in two noteworthy cases. Section III discusses comparative
approaches to excessive pricing adopted in Europe and the United
States. This is followed, in Section IV, by an exposition of the role of
consumer detriment as a unique, but appropriate, qualif‌ier of the South
African prohibition. Section V provides a critical analysis of the self-
correction, innovation and error costs arguments commonly put for-
ward in support of a non-interventionist stance. Section VI consolidates
a new understanding of consumer detriment and advocates a context-
oriented consumer-detriment enquiry. Drawing on the analysis con-
ducted in the previous section, it also provides a distillation of some
pertinent factors to be considered in the enquiry, and offers a suggestion
on the approach to be adopted moving forward. This is followed, in
Section VII, by some concluding remarks.
1
Competition Act 89 of 1998.
(2017) 29 SA MERC LJ
174
© Juta and Company (Pty) Ltd
II THE SOUTH AFRICAN PROHIBITION ON EXCESSIVE
PRICING
(a) The legislative framework
Section 8 of the Act deals with the abuse of a dominant position. While
the bulk of the section focuses on exclusionary acts, provision is made
for addressing a single exploitative practice — excessive pricing.
2
Section
8(a) of the Act prohibits a dominant f‌irm from ‘charg[ing] an excessive
price to the detriment of consumers’. This innately nebulous prohibi-
tion is qualif‌ied by section 1 of the Act, which def‌ines an excessive price
as a price which ‘bears no reasonable relation to the economic value of
[the] good or service [on offer]’ and which is higher than that economic
value.
3
This def‌inition was incorporated into our legislation as a direct
import from the judgment of the European Communities Court of
Justice in United Brands Company and United Brands Continentaal B.V.
v Commission of the European Communities.
4
A key feature of the
def‌inition is its reference to ‘economic value’ — a term that is not
def‌ined in the Act.
The excessive-pricing prohibition is one of only two per se prohibi-
tions in section 8.
5
Therefore, a successful prosecution on this basis is
not reliant on proof of anti-competitive harm; nor can it be defended by
establishing a pro-competitive gain.
6
Yet, interpreting and applying the
prohibition in a factual context is by no means simple. A competition
authority hearing an excessive pricing complaint will be required to
grapple with a host of vexing issues. It will need somehow to determine
the economic value of the goods or service — a task that necessarily
involves an interrogation of complex economic theories and arguments,
and which may be thwarted by seemingly ‘insurmountable technical
2
Incidentally, s 48(1)(a)(i) of the Consumer Protection Act 68 of 2008 also imposes
constraints on pricing practices, albeit without limiting the operation thereof to dominant
f‌irms. The section states that ‘[a] supplier must not offer to supply, supply, or enter into an
agreement to supply, any goods or services at a price that is unfair, unreasonable or unjust ... ’.
Nevertheless, a detailed consideration of s 48(1)(a)(i) falls outside the scope of this paper.
3
Section 1(1)(ix) of the Competition Act.
4
United Brands Company and United Brands Continental BV v Commission of the European
Communities Case 27/76, [1978] ECR 207 paras 248–250.
5
The other being the s 8(b) prohibition on refusing to allow a competitor access to an
essential facility when it is economically feasible to do so.
6
Lewis, Enforcing Competition Rules in South Africa: Thieves at the Dinner Table (Edward
Elgar Publishing 2012) 161.
EXCESSIVE PRICING IN SOUTH AFRICAN COMPETITION LAW 175
© Juta and Company (Pty) Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT